FISCAL DEFICIT AND RESERVE BANK OF INDIA
January 15, 2019
Fiscal Deficit and RBI
This refers to Arup Roychudhury’s report “Non-tax revenue target may fall
short despite RBI interim payout” (Business Standard, January 15, 2019). The
bold statement by the Finance Minister that “I don’t see any shortfall in
non-tax revenues,” quoted in the report and the pressure from GOI on PSUs and
RBI for advance payments against future dividends/surplus income (RBI’s
accounting year is July-June) gives one a feeling that there is some attempt on
the part of finance ministry at what is known as window-dressing in the banking
parlour, to camouflage fiscal deficit. This has become more glaring and more
RBI-focused since 2017.
Perhaps a re-reading of Dr Raghuram Rajan’s Delhi (St Stephen’s College)
speech of September 3,2016, a day before he laid down RBI Governorship may help
FM to bring more transparency in accounting practices and manage the fiscal
deficit issue transparently. Relevant excerpts:
“A fundamental lesson in economics is there is no free lunch. This can be
seen in the matter of the RBI dividend: Some commentators seem to suggest that
public sector banks could be recapitalized entirely if only the RBI paid a
larger dividend to the Government. Let me explain why matters are not so
simple.
If what follows is complicated, trust me, it is. But pay attention,
students, especially because it is about your money. I am sure you will
understand. How does the RBI generate surplus profits?
We, of course, print the currency held by the public, as well as issue
deposits (i.e. reserves) to commercial banks. Those are our fixed liabilities.
As we issue these liabilities, we buy financial assets from the
market. We do not pay interest on our liabilities. However the financial
assets we hold, typically domestic and foreign government bonds, do pay
interest. So we generate a large net interest income simply because we pay
nothing on virtually all our liabilities.
Our total costs, largely for currency printing and banker commissions,
Amount to only about 1/7th of our total net interest income. So we earn a large surplus profit because of
the RBI’s role as the manager of the country’s currency. This belongs entirely
to the country’s citizens.
Therefore, after setting aside
what is needed to be retained as equity capital to maintain the creditworthiness
of the RBI, the RBI Board pays
Out the remaining surplus to the RBI’s owner, the Government.
The RBI Board has decided it wants the RBI to have an international AAA
rating so that RBI can undertake international transactions easily,
even when the Government is in perceived difficulty– in the midst of the
Taper Tantrum, no bank questioned our ability to deliver on the FCNR(B) swaps,
even though the liability could have been tens of thousands of crores. Based
on sophisticated risk analysis by the
RBI’s staff, the Board has decided in the last three years that the RBI’s
equity position, currently around 10 lakh crores, is enough for the purpose. It
therefore has paid out the entire surplus generated to the Government,
amounting to about Rs66,000 crores
each in the last two years, without holding anything back. This is of the order
of magnitude of the dividends paid by the entire public sector to the
Government.
In my three years at the RBI, we have paid almost as much dividend to the
government as in the entire previous decade. Yet some suggest we
should pay more, a special dividend over and above the surplus we
generate. Even if it were legally possible to pay unrealized surplus (it is
not), and even if the Board were convinced a higher dividend would not
compromise the creditworthiness of the RBI, there is a more fundamental
economic reason why a special dividend would not help the Government with its
budgetary constraints.
Here’s why: Much of the surplus we make comes from the interest we get on
government assets or from the capital gains we make off other market
participants. When we pay this to the government as dividends,
We are putting back into the system the money we made from it – there
is no additional money printing or reserve creation involved. But when we
pay a special dividend to the government, we have to create additional
permanent reserves, or more colloquially, print money.
Every year, we have in mind a growth rate of permanent reserves
consistent with the economy’s cash needs and our inflation goals. Given that
budgeted growth rate, to accommodate the special dividend
we will have to withdraw an equivalent amount of money from the public by
selling government bonds in our portfolio (or alternatively,
doing fewer open market purchases than we budgeted). Of course, the Government can use the special
dividend to spend, reducing its public borrowing by that amount. But the RBI will have to sell
bonds of exactly that amount to the public in order to stick to its target for
money creation.
The overall net sale of Government bonds by the Government and the
RBI combined to the public (that is, the effective public sector
borrowing requirement) will not change. But the entire objective of financing
Government spending with a special RBI dividend is to reduce overall Government
bond sales to the public. That objective is not achieved!
The bottom line is that the RBI should transfer to the government the
entire surplus, retaining just
enough buffers that are consistent with good central bank risk management
practice. Indeed, this year the Board paid out an extra 8,000 crores than was
promised to the Government around budget time.
Separately, the government can infuse capital into the banks. The two
decisions need not be linked.
There are no creative ways of extracting more money from the RBI– there is no
free lunch! Instead, the Government should acknowledge its substantial equity
position in the RBI and subtract it from its outstanding debt when it announces
its net debt position. That would satisfy all concerned without monetary
damage.
If what I have said just now seems complicated, it is, but it is also the
correct economic reasoning. Similar detailed rationales lead us to turn
down demands to cut interest rates in the face of high inflation, to
depreciate or appreciate the exchange rate depending on the whim of the moment,
to use foreign exchange reserves to fund projects, to display forbearance in
classifying bad loans or waived farmer loans as
NPAs, and so on...
We have been tasked with a job of maintaining macroeconomic stability,
and often that task requires us to refuse seemingly obvious and attractive
proposals. The reason why we have to do what we have to do may not be easy for
every unspecialized person, even ones with substantial economics training, to
grasp quickly.
Of course, we still must explain
to the best of our ability but we also need to create a structure where the
public trusts the central bank to do the right thing. This then is why we need
a trusted independent central
Bank.”
M G Warrier, Mumbai
Comments